Source: Continuous Improvement Associates http://www.exponentialimprovement.com/cms/labor.shtml Social Issues
Added 4/17/14 Note: See also "Free market" ideologues believe that wages are determined by labor market supply and demand. It isn't true, but it's such a powerful belief that they ignore, or don't even recognize, national policies that subvert this simplistic notion. This article explains why this free market fantasy is false. It begins by examining growth and infrastructure backlog issues and then examines unemployment. They are related, so please be patient. The "free market for labor" myth The "free market for labor" myth is that unions and a minimum wage are interference in the free market. While this is superficially true, these are actually responses to the already prior and overriding interference in the economy by the Federal Reserve. The interference? Federal Reserve policy rigs demand to assure there are always more people who want jobs than there are jobs. This understanding of how Federal Reserve Board policies affect employment and unemployment came to me as I worked to understand the dynamics of growth. I've come to realize that over the long run: Why do we have infrastructure backlogs? From Poverty to Potholes ... The most common tactic of whats called "economic development" is to lower taxes and increase subsidies to businesses to attract them. But the result is an escalating "my region can impose lower taxes and regulations than your region" competition between regions. Because Fed policy allows only so many jobs to be created, it's a zero-sum game for states to compete by giving incentives to companies to get them to locate in their state. Art Rolnick, an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, also points out that Congress Should End the Economic War Among the States because it results in a negative return on investment. His recommendation instead? Invest in Early Childhood Development on a Large Scale for a positive return on investment. The result of these "tax wars" is a nationwide infrastructure backlog of $1.6 trillion. this backlog is rising at a rate of 9.25% per year, many times the rate of inflation. And, as we can all see, its happening in Colorado Springs, too. In Nov. 2000 Dave Zelenok, Group Support Manager Public Works, said that, "if things keep going the way they are, well be facing a $3 - 4 billion backlog" in Colorado Springs in the next 10 - 20 years. Now its logical for every region to want to compete by lowering taxes and regulations
its called being "business-friendly." But a "logical for every individual region" strategy leads to infrastructure backlogs and declines in efficiency and competitiveness for every region and therefore for the nation as a whole. Logical actions in each individual region are collectively insane. This is an example of what economists call the "bounded rationality" of human decision-making. As regional infrastructure backlogs grow and services decline, regions are led to promote more development in order to gain tax revenue. This provides some immediate relief, but years later the increased load on the infrastructure creates an even larger backlog. This prompts regions to promote even more growth for more immediate relief. This is called "addiction." It is the same structure as addiction to drugs: feel good in the short term even though long term health suffers. Because theres a long delay before the infrastructure demands arise, its easy to ignore, and/or obfuscate, the connection. Of course, addiction of any kind is not a solution. No one can sell a product at a loss and make it up in volume. Fine, but what's this got to do with jobs and unemployment? Jobs and unemployment Regions are virtually forced to compete because U.S. government policy only allows so many jobs to be created in the United States. In its drive to control inflation, the Federal Reserve Board keys monetary policy and interest rates to a NAIRU (Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment), which the Fed generally believes is on the order of 5 or 6%. For example, if the Federal Reserve fears inflation from any cause and believes too many jobs are created, or believes unemployment is too low (below its NAIRU target), the Fed raises interest rates or shrinks the money supply to slow the economy and reduce demand for labor. Theres lower demand because theres less investment and fewer people working and therefore less upward pressure on prices. It used to be that the Fed thought NAIRU was 6% or more. But in the 90s the graphs below show Fed policies produced substantial job growth and allowed unemployment to go down to 4% thanks to fiscally responsible tax increases in 1993. While wages went up slightly, this confirmed the vast reservoir of labor available to meet the greater demand.
[Note: BLS data in Apr 2005 shows 275K more jobs added between Jan 2000 and Aug 2004 than were shown in BLS data from Sep 2004. Strange or Fudged? See below the BLS response to my inquiry as to why.] So employment over the long run depends on the NAIRU (in the short run it depends on aggregate demand). The Federal Reserve pursues this policy in the belief that it must do so to avoid an inflationary wage-price spiral (increasing prices resulting in higher wages and even higher prices, etc.). Some dont believe the Fed reacts to employment in this way, but the stock market "knows." When the economy is strong, investors tend to sell when there is either a good unemployment report (unemployment falls) or a good "jobs report" (an expansion of the number of people employed), because they know the Federal Reserve is likely to raise interest rates to "cool the economy."
Fed policy and unemployment The total number of jobs in the U.S. is determined by Fed policy, with the result that nationally there are always more people than there are jobs. So tax competition between regions does not "create jobs;" it simply shifts jobs among regions. It creates higher growth in some regions and lower growth in others, but it does not decrease (overall) unemployment. I didnt believe this until I plotted the graph below showing that regions with higher growth do not on the average have greater reductions in unemployment. It shows that higher growth rates in Metropolitan Statistical Areas between 1997 and 1998 did not produce a more positive "change in employment" between 1998 and 1999. The reason is that people who are out of work in one region move to higher-growth regions.
Find more graphs of "unemployment" and "change in unemployment" vs. regional growth rates at the end of this file (pdf, 178K). There's much scatter in many of the graphs and no clear trend. Many "unemployment" graphs do show reduced unemployment, but continued low unemployment would require unsustainable growth rates. Real unemployment This effect might seem more dramatic than one would expect for a 5 or 6% official unemployment. However, official unemployment is vastly understated. As shown in the figures below, because job growth hasn't kept up with population growth and because some categories of unemployed aren't officially counted, unemployment is more like 10%.
And as the figure below shows, "official" unemployment, U-3, is a vast understatement.
A graphic illustration that there is vast unemployment, understated even by these graphs: 25 thousand apply for 325 jobs at a new Wal-Mart in January 2006 (another link to this article or google: "325 jobs" Wal-Mart). Another graphic example: In March 2007 in Detroit 26,000 apply for 1,000 casino jobs. Unemployment is typically understood to be higher in Europe than in Japan and the U.S., but data shows that rates of unemployment are not all that much different ....
And this doesnt even include other categories that provide sources of labor. Lester Thurow in an interview on his 1996 book, The Future of Capitalism, estimated slack in the labor force at more like 30% (including those officially counted, 5.7%, dont meet the official test, 4.5%, part-time, 3.4%, on-call, 1.5%, disappeared, 4.5%, and self-employed many of whom are underemployed, 6.1%). And we cant compare a 6% unemployment today to a 6% unemployment in the 80s because contingency workers part-timers, temporaries and contract workers who lack full benefits and job security make up a greater part of the labor force, accounting for as many as 30 million of the workers (out of ~137 million employed). The number of mainly low-wage temporaries has tripled over the last dozen years (Denver Post, 9/5/94). It shouldn't be surprising that the "official unemployment" data is an underestimate. No government would want to admit that national policy is set to assure that on the order of 20% of the workforce (1 in 5) is unemployed or underemployed. Because 20 - 30% of the working population wants work or more work or work for which they're better qualified, regions are essentially playing "musical chairs." Because some regions are sure to not have enough jobs, the added value of any one region zero. So because there is only so many jobs and only so much economic growth allowed, companies can say, "Give us a deal, or well go elsewhere." Companies can demand concessions, just as a sports team demands that a city build a tax-payer-funded stadium, if it wants the team to move there. In the book, Co-opetition, by Brandenberger and Nalebuff, they call this "sacking the cities." The counterpart for Fed policy is "sacking the workers." So when jobs shift from one area of the country to another driven by "economic development" tax wars and subsidies, there's churning as people move across the country to follow those jobs, but no more total jobs are created. The Fed assures there's a zero-sum game competition among regions that hurts all regions. The low wages parallel and unions Because there are more people than there are jobs, the added value of any one person is also zero. Employers can say, "Some people are going to be without a job, so take the job at this wage or someone else will." This is why wages are stagnant at the bottom and why there's a minimum wage. Many say that a minimum wage is an interference in the "free market" for labor, but they ignore the Feds prior interference. There is no free market for labor. Forming a union and bargaining together is the only way for workers to overcome this "musical chairs" dynamic in which some will always be without jobs and the added value of any one worker is zero. Unions prevent companies from playing one worker off against another using the argument: "Someone's going to be without a job ... do you want it to be you? ... take it at this wage or else it will be you." It's this dynamic that's led to increasing profits, but falling wages:
In addition to Fed policies, labor laws have also undermined union strength. So-called "right to work" laws were passed to undermine union strength by letting some employees "free ride" on those who do pay dues; the equivalent in our democracy would be letting people opt out of paying taxes and still get the benefits of roads and national defense. Furthermore, capital organizes itself in corporations and a labor union organization counterpart is a necessary counterbalance to corporate power. It's difficult to understand the antipathy to unions because corporations are virtual dictatorships, whereas unions are democracies. So unions have challenges that corporations do not; democracies are much more difficult to manage. It really doesn't make sense that "union bosses" are so villainized. After all "corporate bosses" have more power than "union bosses;" look at how CEO pay has increased, even for companies that subsequently failed. . The insufficient taxes & low wages parallel So theres an important analogy between taxes and wages. Taxes can be considered "regional wages" that allow regions to maintain a certain quality of life, just as wages allow people to maintain a certain quality of life. Regions have infrastructure backlogs for the same reason that many people do not make a living wage. This is a surprising example of how were all in this together. People stuck in traffic, people in low wage jobs, and tax limitation advocates all have complaints that originate from the same structural cause: Federal Reserve policy that suppresses demand for workers. But these groups are usually in conflict because they dont understand this. Think what would happen if they joined forces to push for policy changes that would actually solve their problems!
For more on growth, see the Growth Facts of Life and the much more detailed Tangle of Growth. Addenda: 1. In the 49 months since the recession began in March 2001 through May 2005, there has been a net increase of 782,000 jobs. To keep up with population growth over this period, 137,000 jobs must be added every month. Over 49 months, that's 6,713,000 jobs that are needed just to stay even. That means that over this period there's a job backlog of 5,931,000 jobs. That 6 million job shortfall never seems to get attention in the media. 2. Somehow the official BLS data in May 2005 shows there were 275,000 more jobs added from Jan 2000 through Aug 2004 than was the case for the same data series that was official in Sep 2004. [Go to http://data.bls.gov/cgi-bin/surveymost?bls and retrieve Series CES0000000001 for the current data. Had I not saved it, I wouldn't have the data as presented in Sep. 04.] Where did the extra 275,000 jobs came from? The response from BLS, for which even more research would be required for a clear explanation: From: cesinfo <cesinfo@BLS.GOV> Top of Page |